Faculty of law blogs / UNIVERSITY OF OXFORD

The Ascertainable Standards that Define the Boundaries of the SEC’s Rulemaking Authority

Author(s)

Bernard S. Sharfman
Senior Corporate Governance Fellow, RealClearFoundation

Posted

Time to read

5 Minutes

In March 2022, prior to the publication of the SEC’s proposed rule on climate-related disclosures—The Enhancement and Standardization of Climate-Related Disclosures for Investors (‘Proposed Rule’)—former SEC Commissioner Allison Lee gave a speech where she argued that the Commission can do whatever it wants in regard to climate change related disclosures: ‘We have broad authority to prescribe disclosure requirements as necessary or appropriate in the public interest or for the protection of investors.’  Such a conclusory statement brings to the fore a critical issue—what are the legal limitations of the SEC's rulemaking authority in general and, more specifically, in the area of climate-related disclosures?

Not surprisingly, comment letters in response to the Proposed Rule identified such limitations including those based on the First Amendment.  Most importantly, the US Supreme Court’s decision in West Virginia v Environmental Protection Agency established that the ‘major questions’ doctrine (a legal doctrine which limits an agency’s power to act on issues of ‘economic and political significance’ without clear authorization from Congress) may be a significant impediment to the finalization of the Proposed Rule. 

My new article, ‘The Ascertainable Standards that Define the Boundaries of the SEC’s Rulemaking Authority,’  presents a new argument against finalization. This argument finds its authority in the ‘ascertainable standards’ that are found in the statutes, the Securities Act of 1933 and the Securities Exchange Act of 1934 (the ‘Acts’), that underlie the Proposed Rule.  Ascertainable standards are both policy objectives that the Board must use in its decision-making, including rulemaking, and what a reviewing court will use when determining if the Board has acted in an ‘arbitrary and capricious’ manner or has crossed the boundaries of its statutory authority under Section 706 of the Administrative Procedures Act (‘APA’).  

There are three ascertainable standards in the Acts: (1) ‘the protection of investors’ , (2) promoting ‘efficiency, competition, and capital formation,’ and (3) materiality.  This triad of standards can be broken down into two policy objectives and one policy constraint. Investor protection, pertaining only to being informed of firm specific investment risk, is the primary objective.  Promoting ‘efficiency, competition, and capital formation’ is a secondary objective. ‘Materiality can be thought of as a “soft” constraint, a condition that is required unless a non-material disclosure is necessary to facilitate the two policy objectives.’  Moreover, looking at the Acts through this lens makes clear that materiality, contrary to mainstream thinking, does not stand alone as a means to limit the SEC’s rulemaking authority.

The identification of ascertainable standards, found in all statutes with a regulatory component (‘regulatory statute’), begins with the nondelegation doctrine and its ‘intelligible principle’ test. The nondelegation doctrine was created by the US Supreme Court to help enforce our Constitutional separation of powers.  As such, it requires Congress to refrain from abdicating or transferring its legislative functions (Article I, Section 1 of the US Constitution) to another branch of government (eg, broad grants of discretionary authority to an administrative agency) unless Congress ‘shall lay down by legislative act an intelligible principle to which the person or body authorized to [exercise the delegated authority] is directed to conform….’

As stated by Justice Rehnquist in his concurring opinion in Industrial Union Dept., AFL-CIO v American Petroleum Institute, the identification of an intelligible principle is critical in directing the decision-making of an agency, including its rulemaking, and for the courts when it reviews an agency rule under the APA:   

‘As formulated and enforced by this Court, the nondelegation doctrine serves three important functions. First, and most abstractly, it ensures to the extent consistent with orderly governmental administration that important choices of social policy are made by Congress, the branch of our Government most responsive to the popular will. Second, the doctrine guarantees that, to the extent Congress finds it necessary to delegate authority, it provides the recipient of that authority with an “intelligible principle” to guide the exercise of the delegated discretion. Third, and derivative of the second, the doctrine ensures that courts charged with reviewing the exercise of delegated legislative discretion will be able to test that exercise against ascertainable standards. (citations omitted).’

In the Public Interest

The triad of ascertainable standards are also used to fill in the blanks of what Congress meant when it repeatedly inserted the vague term of ‘in the public interest’ into the Acts. This term only becomes understandable when it is animated with these ascertainable standards.  In this context ‘in the public interest’ can be thought of as a maximization problem with two constraints. What is being maximized when the SEC takes an action, such as promulgating climate-related disclosures, is ‘investor protection.’ This is the primary mission of the Acts.  Moreover, based on a historical understanding of the Acts, the definition of investor protection is limited to informing investors of firm specific investment risk. 

The first constraint of this maximization problem is actually the secondary objective, the promotion of efficiency, competition, and capital formation. To specify this objective as a constraint, an SEC action can never have an expected negative effect on the promotion of efficiency, competition, and capital formation. However, the expected impact can be neutral and most definitely positive. The second constraint is materiality. Congress has provided significant evidence that it intended the SEC to focus on material disclosures as the primary means of protecting investors. Nonetheless, non-material disclosures may be required if it can be shown that they advance investor protection and have at least a neutral impact on the promotion of efficiency, competition, and capital formation.

The Overall Impact

What should also be apparent is that no matter which administration is in power, the more one can identify ascertainable standards with substantive meaning, the more restraints Congress places on an agency’s discretionary authority to act. In that regard, investor protection; making sure disclosures will actually enhance efficiency, competition, and capital formation and not lead to their reduction; and the constraint of materiality requires the SEC to be very cautious in its approach to promulgating rules, including climate-related disclosures. 

Moreover, it would not be surprising to find that if an ascertainable standard review of all SEC rules and interpretations were to occur, many of them would be found to violate the boundaries of authority created by the identified standards. For example, the SEC takes the position that it has extremely broad authority to compel public companies to include shareholder proposals on social issues in their proxy statements.  By taking this position, the SEC is showing a blatant disregard for the three ascertainable standards that permeate the Acts and the boundaries of authority that they create.

What the SEC Can Do in Requiring Climate-Related Disclosures

When these ascertainable standards are applied to the Proposed Rule, a court is likely to find that the SEC has exceeded its authority.  For example, none of the required disclosures involving Scope emissions meet the requirements for investor protection or are material to reasonable investors.  Thus, the Proposed Rule is at risk of being set aside in whole or in part. 

If so, what can the SEC do in the way of climate-related disclosures?  Fortunately, the required approach is already found in the 2010 Guidance where the focus is on disclosing material risk factors ‘that make an investment in the registrant speculative or risky’ or ‘are reasonably likely to have a material effect on [a public company’s or registrant’s] financial condition or operating performance.’ However, certain updates are definitely required.  Since 2010, investors have become more aware of the risks that climate change has had and may have on our economy and clearly an update of that guidance with more examples of firm specific investment risk that a reporting company needs to disclose would be useful. For example, investors becoming better informed of low probability, high impact climate change events that may materially harm a reporting company.  Moreover, even if the risk of these events has already been disclosed, further disclosure may be required if the probability and/or impact of such events have increased over the years. 

The author’s complete article is available here.

A version of this post was previously published in The Federalist Society linked here.

The opinions expressed here are the author’s alone and do not represent the official position of any organization with which he is currently affiliated.

Bernard S. Sharfman is a Senior Corporate Governance Fellow at the RealClearFoundation, a Research Fellow at the Law & Economics Center at George Mason University's Antonin Scalia Law School, and a member of the Journal of Corporation Law's editorial advisory board.

 

Share

With the support of