Faculty of law blogs / UNIVERSITY OF OXFORD

Authorizations to issue shares and disapply pre-emption rights: evidence from Belgium and France

Author(s)

Tom Vos
Visiting Professor, Jean-Pierre Blumberg Chair at the University of Antwerp (Belgium)

Posted

Time to read

4 Minutes

In Europe, shareholder approval and pre-emption rights have traditionally fulfilled an important role in protecting shareholders in listed corporations against excessive dilution in share issuances. However, these protections also make it costlier and slower to raise capital through share issuances. That is why countries generally allow shareholders to authorize the board of directors to issue shares without shareholder approval and without pre-emption rights—within certain limits. The protection offered by pre-emption rights and shareholder approval therefore depends on the extent to which shareholders are willing to approve authorizations to issue shares and disapply pre-emption rights.

In a recent working paper, I provide new empirical evidence on the flexibility of such authorizations in practice in French and Belgian listed corporations. Proxy advisors and (associations of) asset managers have adopted guidelines on the maximum size for authorizations—typically 50% of the legal capital for authorizations to issue shares with pre-emption rights, and 10% of the legal capital for authorizations to issue shares without pre-emption rights (although Glass Lewis is more flexible for Belgium, with thresholds of 100% and 20%, respectively).

However, my evidence shows that these guidelines are often not followed in Belgium and France: the 50% limit for pre-emptive share issuances is not followed by 50% of Belgian corporations and 7% of French corporations, while the 10% limit for non-pre-emptive share issuances is not followed by 69% of Belgian corporations and 30% of French corporations. This stands in stark contrast with the situation in the UK, where previous research has found that the Pre-emption Guidelines and Share Capital Management Guidelines (which impose similar restrictions on authorizations) are widely observed by UK corporations.

I also provide empirical evidence through a multiple regression model that authorizations are generally more flexible in corporations with high levels of insider ownership, corporations with a smaller market capitalization, and Belgian corporations. I also offer several potential explanations for these differences.

First, higher insider ownership generally makes it easier for insiders to control the vote in the general meeting and force through more flexible authorizations that benefit them. This does not necessarily mean that high levels of insider ownership are inefficient, as controlling shareholders may also have benefits.

Second, small corporations may have more flexible authorizations than large corporations because small corporations generally receive less attention from investors, activists, the media, and research analysts. Alternatively, it may be that smaller corporations have higher capital needs, and therefore need more flexible authorizations.

Finally, the difference between Belgium and France could be explained by differences in the legal framework. Authorizations in Belgium are almost invariably given for the maximum period allowed by the law, five years. In France, the law imposes a shorter maximum duration on authorizations of 26 months. If shareholders can vote more often on authorizations, they have more opportunities to hold insiders accountable, which could explain the stricter authorizations in France. In addition, French law requires that shareholders vote on separate resolutions for authorizations for share issuances with pre-emption rights and authorizations for share issuances without pre-emption rights, while this is not the law or market practice in Belgium. Separate votes for pre-emptive and non-pre-emptive authorizations can ensure that shareholders are not coerced into voting for excessive authorizations for non-pre-emptive share issuances out of an unwillingness of voting against any form of authorization for the corporation, which would likely be inefficient. The lack of separate votes can explain why only 8 of 84 Belgian corporations have adopted stricter authorizations for non-pre-emptive share issuances than for pre-emptive share issuances.

The paper also analyzed whether authorizations to issue shares could be used as a takeover defense. Here, a similar picture emerges: despite the fact that the guidelines of proxy advisors and asset managers generally oppose takeover defenses, more than 40% of Belgian corporations and 28% of French corporations have an authorization to issue shares that can be used as a takeover defense. Again, such takeover defenses are more common in corporations with high levels of insider ownership and corporations with a smaller market capitalization. Institutional ownership is also significantly negatively associated with the likelihood of adopting an authorization that can be used as a takeover defense. The difference between Belgium and France is no longer statistically significant, however. A possible explanation is that the default rule in Belgium is that authorizations to issue shares cannot be used as a takeover defense, while the default rule is the opposite in France. This difference in the default rule may be enough to counterbalance the general trend of more flexible authorizations in Belgium than in France.

The empirical analysis in the paper was not designed to test whether the currently adopted authorizations are too flexible or too strict. Nevertheless, I do believe that the differences in the legal framework identified between Belgium and France could inspire policy proposals that give shareholders a larger say in the flexibility of authorizations to issue shares and disapply pre-emption rights. For example, the legal rule in France that requires a shareholder vote every two years and a separate shareholder vote on the authorization to disapply pre-emption rights could also be introduced in Belgium. It is possible that such reforms will not be effective in reducing the size of authorizations, either because shareholders believe the current flexible authorizations are efficient, or because a controlling shareholder makes it impossible for other shareholders to have an impact on the shareholder vote anyway. Even in that case, these policy proposals would be relatively harmless, as the costs of implementing them are limited: management may need to spend some extra effort in convincing shareholders that the authorization is justified, but the authorization can simply be approved during the annual general meeting that would have to be organized anyway. In addition, corporations would retain the possibility to adopt more flexible authorizations if this is efficient, provided that they can convince a sufficient number of shareholders of this.

That is why I argue that these low-cost proposals can help to empower shareholders to decide how the balance between flexibility and accountability should be struck with regards to authorizations to issue shares.

Tom Vos is a full-time visiting professor at the Jean-Pierre Blumberg Chair, University of Antwerp.

Share

With the support of